It's Like Money, but With No Dead Presidents

Slate Magazine - Tim Harford - I was recently invited to appear on radio to provide the economists'
perspective on the costs and benefits of local exchange trading schemes,
which are alternative currencies that circulate around a small community.
This made me scratch my head a bit. I could not think of any real benefits,
but then I could not really think of any serious costs, either.

Proponents of community currencies argue that they have social, economic,
and environmental advantages. BerkShares Inc., which organizes a local
currency in Massachusetts, claims that the currency helps area businesses
connect with their customers but also strengthens the regional economy by
favoring locals. In the United Kingdom, "transition towns," which are
seeking to use less oil, are exploring the environmental benefits of local
currencies.

The common-sense economic case for these currencies was summed up for me by
John Walker, acting treasurer of Brixton LETS in London: "They're more
appropriate for local communities, because the money doesn't drain out of
the local community."

That seems plausible: The money (Brixton bricks) goes 'round and 'round
Brixton and isn't sucked away by the insidious multinationals of neighboring
Clapham. But this is one of those cases in which common sense lets us down.
Money, whether pounds or Brixton bricks, isn't wealth. It's just a way of
keeping accounts, and swapping one system of accounts for another isn't
going to alter the basic productive potential of Brixton.

True, community currencies may very gently encourage trade with locals
rather than strangers. But the gains from more trade with locals are more
than offset by the losses from less trade with strangers. Otherwise,
economic sanctions would be a blessing. That is why no community-currency
movement tries seriously to restrict broader trade. Everyone knows that is a
recipe for return to the Dark Ages.

There have been times and places when national currencies have so
malfunctioned that community currencies would have been preferable: Weimar
Germany, modern Zimbabwe, perhaps also the Depression-era United States,
where some community currencies briefly flourished. There is also a healthy
debate in economics over the appropriate size of a currency union, but few
serious economists think that the optimal currency area is the size of
Brixton or the southern Berkshires.

Nor are the environmental benefits of community currencies terribly
persuasive. Local trade sounds environmentally friendly, but it is a
distraction: The environmental cost of driving to the shops or growing food
on inappropriate local land is far greater than the cost of the carbon
emissions of long-range shipping.

The real benefits, if they exist, are not economic but social, and best
explained not by an economist like me but by a sociologist such as Ed Collom
of the University of Southern Maine.

Collom's work looks, at first glance, like bad news for the
community-currency movement. He has found, for example, that most currency
schemes in the United States last only a few years before collapsing. The
ones that thrive are in places which already have strong, liberal,
middle-class communities, such as Portland, Ore., or Ithaca, N.Y. In the
Rust Belt areas that would seem to need them more, they have not taken root.
The schemes take a lot of effort to set up: Brixton LETS, for instance,
remains nascent.

But despite the obstacles, Ed Collom is convinced that local currencies can
strengthen neighborhood ties and allow people to make friends: They are a
focal point for the community-minded, even when they do not last.

That is possible. I live near a determined, community-minded entrepreneur
who owns the local cafe, the sort of person who helps to get community
currencies started. But rather than minting a Homerton dollar, she has
founded a traders' association and is trying to set up a street market. I
think she has the right priorities.